Topic Tags:
10 Comments

Inflation is a Product of Ineptitude, Not Misfortune

Peter Smith

Sep 13 2022

16 mins

Economists do little harm outside of government. True, the Sydney-based Australian Bankers’ Association Research Directorate was closed down shortly after I left my position of economic adviser in the mid-1980s, and the State Bank Victoria collapsed while I was chief economist at the beginning of the 1990s. However, I protest my innocence and impotence. I was too uninfluential to be instrumental in defining events. And, let me say, most economists in the private sector are in the same boat. That’s not the case when it comes to government. When in government, and most definitely I include central banks as part of government, there is no limit to the damage economists can do. We are about to live through a time which underscores that baleful reality.

Inflation has been let loose. This has not been the product of happenchance, unforeseeable by those trained in economics or, in fact, by anyone with the slightest interest in economic history. Inflation (a persistent and appreciable rise in the general level of prices) has a long history. One episode which especially piques my interest took place in revolutionary France. It is interesting not simply as an example of inflation but because the powers that be back then, in 1789, acknowledged that issuing paper money (“assignats”) was a risky, inflationary idea.

Florin Aftalion (in The French Revolution: An Economic Interpretation) quotes Count Mirabeau, who saw the problem while trying to put something of a gloss on it:

I would agree with those who describe such an issue as a theft or a loan at sword-point but I would also allow that, in exceptionally critical circumstances, a nation may be forced to have recourse to bills of state. One should banish from the language the infamous term paper money … Under any other circumstances, all paper money is an offence to good faith and to the nation’s liberty; in its circulation, it is a kind of plague.

The plan was to temporarily issue assignats (pictured atop this page), which would be redeemed (and burnt) through the sale of public lands, mostly confiscated church property. The French chemist Antoine Lavoisier, a few years before his untimely guillotined end, demonstrated that church property was worth only 1,050 million assignats against the plan at the time to issue 2,000 million. It would bring about an “increase in value of all things”, he said perceptively, also in 1789.

Alas, the appetite for issuing assignats proved too strong. Up went the price of bread and every­thing else. According to William Doyle (in The Oxford History of the French Revolution), “a nominal 45 billion livres worth of paper was issued between 1790 and 1797, but its total real value (at 1790 prices) was less than a seventh of that.” We are not in that hyper-inflationary league. Nevertheless, the principle applies. Drop too much money into an economy and abracadabra, inflation appears; and not by magic. If Mirabeau and Lavoisier, among others, knew that in 1789 then I don’t think the Reserve Bank’s governor, Philip Lowe, or the Fed’s Jerome Powell or the Bank of England’s Andrew Bailey can profess ignorance of what causes inflation. Yet inflation is what we have. And no one has resigned.

Personally, I don’t think we should be so forgiving of million-dollar-plus-earning potentate economists who royally mess up the very task that they are principally employed and generously paid to get done right. But let me start by giving them the benefit of an excuse of sorts, as a curtain-raiser to my main objective. Not to put too fine a point on it, that objective is to explain why central bankers have bungled and botched their jobs. As I will show, their focus has been, and is, on the wrong economic variable. Another instance of being led astray by the error-strewn Keynesian script.

To the curtain-raiser. Whatever dreadful plight you’re in, it is better to have company. Lost in a wood; better with mates. First, you might be able to share the blame for taking the wrong fork in the path. Second, the baying sounds around you are less frightening than they would be if you were alone. Importantly, everyone has seen those horror movies where those lost split up to find help or a way out. Never a good idea. So it is that the allure of sticking with the crowd partly explains the wrong turns taken collectively in recent times by central banks.

One Australian newspaper headline read, “Costello blasts RBA’s failure”. Another: “RBA under the pump on inflation”. Same kind of the thing in the UK Telegraph: “The Bank of England’s credibility is now severely compromised”. And in the United States, the former Chair of the Fed got into the act: “Bernanke says the Fed’s slow response to inflation was a mistake”.

All of the above comments and many more were made in May and June, when central banks eventually woke up to the fact that the rise in inflation after the end of Covid lockdowns might not be transitory after all. Notice that their enlightenment came en masse. This is not surprising. Their antennas are always pointing in the direction of their international counterparts.

No (first-world) central bank wants to stand out from the crowd. Thus, each can be caught up in the swell—and, to boot, without quite knowing its origin. Often it begins with a consensus built on conventional economic theory. For example, times were tough during and immediately after the recession of 2009-10. Theory pointed to the need for central banks to force interest rates lower. They acted accordingly, more or less in unison. From there, each kept a weather eye on what the others were doing.

No central bank wants to keep interest rates materially lower than its counterpart central banks. Doing so might well reduce the value of its country’s currency and, thereby, cause untoward price rises; initially in imported goods and services. None wants to materially tighten ahead of the rest for fear it will increase the value of its country’s currency and cause additional unemployment; initially in export and import-competing sectors. So, each one is stuck until a new consensus develops. Meanwhile they have the comfort, when things go awry, of being in the same pickle. They can form a laager to counter “untutored” criticisms from those not holding the secret knowledge. And they can find solace in sharing each other’s plight.

This essay appears in September’s Quadrant.
Click here to subscribe and avoid the paywall

None of this implicit collusion would matter if their economic script were sound. They’d move in unison in broadly the right direction. Unfortunately, their Keynesian-derived script is unsound, which brings me to why things have gone wrong. Incidentally, be in no doubt, things have gone badly wrong. Inflation is the worst of economic ills. Incompetence has been at work, akin to pilot error. Though, there’s the difference that pilots face punitive consequences.

Inflation clouds price signals and in so doing complicates investment decision-making. It brings undue enrichment to some (such as wealthy owners of real property) and undue impoverishment to others (such as pensioners with cash savings). And that’s before the “fun” begins, when central bankers hike interest rates to quell the inflation which they’ve previously fuelled.

Hikes in interest rates shock the economic system. The patterns of resource allocation, and borrowing and spending, fitted for low interest rates are suddenly ill-fitted for the new regime. The result is economic distress (for example, for those with large mortgages) and increased unemployment (for example, among those working for heavily-geared businesses). Full-blown recessions can result—not a small thing. It can’t be described as a minor lapse on the part of those charged with preventing inflation in the first place.

It’s best, I believe, to go to Milton Friedman to discover why things have gone wrong. My own choice of Friedman’s extensive writing on monetary economics is his easy-to-read book Free to Choose, first published in 1979, which he wrote with his wife Rose. It’s a marvel of clarity and plain common sense. Common sense because much of economics is common sense when stripped of technical-cum-mathematical embroidery. Look at one of the most foundational concepts in economics; namely, the downward sloping demand curve. It simply says that when the price of a good goes up the demand for it usually goes down, and vice versa. Who in the world wouldn’t reach that conclusion? No economics textbook required.

Friedman promotes a concept which is analogous to the downward sloping demand curve. It is that the more money there is around, the lower its value is likely to be in term of the goods and services each unit of money can buy. The more seashells on the desert island, the fewer the number of fish ten shells can buy. Makes sense. Correspondingly, the more seashells, the higher the price in seashells of each fish. Suppose a giant wave were to hit the island bringing, in its aftermath, a great abundance of seashells. Then the price of each fish would soar. Inflation would hit the island.

The well-known equation MV=PT provides a frame of reference. Equations can be daunting. Relax. This one isn’t.

What it’s saying is that the number of times (V) each unit of money is passed from hand-to-hand times the number of units of money in circulation (M), equals the turnover (T) of goods times their price (P). It’s a truism, an identity. However, it becomes meaningful when it is assumed, as does Friedman, that the value of V is broadly stable, measured over a complete economic cycle. Then an increase in the money supply beyond the rate of increase in production (tied one-to-one with turnover) translates, indubitably, into a rise in prices; and, voila, we have the Quantity Theory of Money. In a nutshell: increases in the money supply beyond increases in real production engender increases in the general level of prices.

Contention surrounds the stability or otherwise of V; the so-called velocity of circulation of money. Keynes in the General Theory considered it to be a “will-o’-the-wisp” and, therefore, entirely unpredictable. If that were so, there would be no way to predict the effect of changes in the money supply on production or prices. Thus, he focused on interest rates as the pivotal factor in determining the pace of economic activity; a first-order error, bequeathed to central bankers.

The behaviour of velocity is an empirical question, which Friedman answered through exhaustive examinations of data. The prime example is his Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. But in Free to Choose he looked at data from Germany, Japan, the UK and Brazil. Everywhere he looked, the money supply and prices rose closely together, with price inflation lagging behind excessive monetary growth by some twelve months or so. Hence his familiar conclusion that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon”.

A highly correlated positive relationship between money and prices means, ipso facto, that the velocity of circulation of money is relatively stable. Otherwise, the close relationship would be undone. QED? Well, perhaps not for Keynesians, or their Modern Monetary Theory cousins, as I explained in “Unmasking Modern Monetary Theory” (Quadrant, July 2019). It would queer their pitch when advocating a combination of deficit spending and low interest rates. It’s time to get a little interrogative with money and its use. Bear with me. It strikes at the flawed thinking of central banks.

Money has various definitions. A narrow one of cash plus at-demand deposits in deposit-taking institutions (so-called M1 money) is the best, I think, when considering the velocity of circulation. This is the category of money principally used as a medium of exchange. However, when looking at some data below, I’ll use broader definitions for Australia and for the US to counter breaks in the series of narrow money. It doesn’t matter too much.

It’s a safe assumption that the amount of money that people and businesses hold to pay their bills is relatively unchanging in any given state of society. Evolution of new payment methods, such as credit cards, will change things to one extent or other. However, the state of the economy from one year to the next is unlikely to change the way money is used in the everyday business of buying and selling. At the same time, it’s recognised by Friedman, and more widely, that the velocity of money falls during economic downturns and rises during upturns. Pro-cyclical movements in velocity, it’s called. What’s going on?

In fact, the degree and the extent to which money is used for buying and selling don’t change. What changes is that during economic downturns extra money is demanded as a safe haven (fewer shares and more bank deposits). What is seen, therefore, as a fall in velocity is deceptive. The money being used for transactions is still turning over at the same rate. It’s just that a greater portion of the total supply of money is held aside; hoarded, if you like. The same reasoning applies in reverse during economic upturns, when velocity is seen to rise.

Take the situation during the recent lockdowns. Governments engaged in spending vast amounts of money to support individuals prevented from working and businesses prevented from operating. Governments sold bonds to fund their expenditure; obviously, increasing taxes wasn’t an option. Central banks set cash rates close to zero to keep interest rates down at the short end and bought up vast quantities of government bonds to keep longer-term rates subdued. The money supply jumped, as it was bound to do. Here’s a snapshot.

In Australia, M3 money, which includes demand and time deposits, increased by an annual 4.7 per cent on average from December 2015 to December 2019. In the following year, it increased by 12.6 per cent and in the year to December 2021 by another 9.3 per cent. Bear in mind too that the narrower definition of money would have likely spurted at an even greater rate in the two years to the end of 2021. (RBA figures)

In the UK, the average annual growth in M1 was 5.9 per cent between 2015 and 2019. In the following two years it averaged 13 per cent per annum. (OECD figures)

In the US, the average annual growth in M2, which includes demand and time deposits, was 5.5 per cent between 2015 and 2019. In the following two years it averaged 18.5 per cent per annum. (Fed figures)

Central bankers orchestrated large increases in the money supply. What did they think would happen? Did they think that the velocity of money would stay down to accommodate the untoward increases in the money supply; or could be safely disregarded as a will-o’-the-wisp, à la Keynes? I don’t know.

At first, the additional supplies of money were hoarded, as economies struggled and people and businesses were fearful of the outlook. Par for the course. But, at the beginning of 2022, once the outlook improved, these hoarded balances came into play—so to speak, from under the mattress into the marketplace. Procyclical velocity, it might be badged. Too much money chasing too few goods, is a more common or garden way of expressing it. And, as is usually the case, inflation is triggered by some untoward event—this time supply chain disruptions and rising energy prices, before the Ukraine conflict began, set inflation afoot. The Ukraine conflict added oil and gas to the fire; or, literally speaking, further constricted the supply of oil and gas. But, make no mistake, particular prices can rise because of, say, bottlenecks. Inflation cannot and will not occur in the absence of excessive growth in the money supply.

This inflation isn’t transitory; if there’s any such thing. By buying up government bonds, central banks allowed the money spent extravagantly by governments during the over-hyped pandemic to flood economies. Of course, there’s blame to share with governments and their treasury officials. Nonetheless, the onus in preventing inflation rests with central bankers.

Quantity matters. The sheer size of the bond buying sprees (quantitative easing on steroids) was the fault. Pushing interest rates down close to zero never makes sense. It’s much more damaging than it is helpful. It tends to encourage over-borrowing, not least on the part of governments. Setting the interest-rate hurdle too low encourages unproductive investments, including on home building. It sets up economies for painful readjustments when the chickens come home to roost, as they now are.

What to do? “That’s easy enough,” according to Friedman. “The government must increase the quantity of money less rapidly.” And he adds a cautionary note: “The most important device for mitigating the side effects [‘slower economic growth and higher than usual unemployment’] is to slow inflation gradually but steadily by a policy announced in advanced and adhered to so it becomes credible.” Why does he propose a gradual approach? In order “to give people time to readjust their arrangements”. Seems eminently sensible. Commonsensical, it might be said.

Go back to the period January to April in Australia. The cash rate is 0.1 per cent. Homebuyers line up for cheap housing loans, perhaps given confidence by earlier statements from the Reserve Bank that near-zero rates would last for a long time—to beyond the end of 2023, according to a media release dated November 2, 2021. From bad forecasting to reality: in May the cash rate is upped by 25 basis points, and in June, July and August by another 50 basis points each month, with more to come promised*. To wit: “The [Reserve Bank] Board expects to take further steps in the process of normalising monetary conditions over the months ahead …” Is this gradual, do you think? Or a tad sudden? Never mind, be thankful for small mercies. In the US, the Fed seems to have settled on jumps of 75 basis points.

Central banks appear to be intent on showing how tough and resolute they are in dealing with those who’ve irresponsibly overextended themselves. Or, more likely, are showing how panicked they are at having let the inflation genie out of the bottle.

I have no idea whether central banks are monitoring monetary growth. Friedman refers to the “Fed’s obsession with interest rates” rather than with “controlling the quantity of money”. Remember he wrote this in 1979. Nothing seems to have changed. The difficulty is that keeping interest rates too low resulted in excessive growth in the money supply and, inevitably, inflation. Making interest rates too high, too quickly, in the current circumstances, could result in a slew of bad debts, curtailment of bank lending and a corresponding collapse in monetary growth. Such a collapse would both reflect and presage more economic distress than is necessary or sensible to cure inflation. It might be termed getting it wrong on the way up and on the way down. With a nod to Oscar Wilde, to err on the way up may be regarded as ineptitude; to err also on the way down looks like delinquency.

* Promise fulfilled. Another 50 basis points on 6 September. Promise renewed. More to come.

Peter Smith is a frequent contributor to Quadrant and Quadrant Online

Peter Smith

Peter Smith

Regular contributor

Peter Smith

Regular contributor

Comments

Join the Conversation

Already a member?

What to read next

  • Letters: Authentic Art and the Disgrace of Wilgie Mia

    Madam: Archbishop Fisher (July-August 2024) does not resist the attacks on his church by the political, social or scientific atheists and those who insist on not being told what to do.

    Aug 29 2024

    6 mins

  • Aboriginal Culture is Young, Not Ancient

    To claim Aborigines have the world's oldest continuous culture is to misunderstand the meaning of culture, which continuously changes over time and location. For a culture not to change over time would be a reproach and certainly not a cause for celebration, for it would indicate that there had been no capacity to adapt. Clearly this has not been the case

    Aug 20 2024

    23 mins

  • Pennies for the Shark

    A friend and longtime supporter of Quadrant, Clive James sent us a poem in 2010, which we published in our December issue. Like the Taronga Park Aquarium he recalls in its 'mocked-up sandstone cave' it's not to be forgotten

    Aug 16 2024

    2 mins